Do you want to publish a course? Click here

On the compensator in the Doob-Meyer decomposition of the Snell envelope

81   0   0.0 ( 0 )
 Added by Dominykas Norgilas
 Publication date 2017
  fields
and research's language is English




Ask ChatGPT about the research

Let $G$ be a semimartingale, and $S$ its Snell envelope. Under the assumption that $Ginmathcal{H}^1$, we show that the finite-variation part of $S$ is absolutely continuous with respect to the decreasing part of the finite-variation part of $G$. In the Markovian setting, this enables us to identify sufficient conditions for the value function of the optimal stopping problem to belong to the domain of the extended (martingale) generator of the underlying Markov process. We then show that the textit{dual} of the optimal stopping problem is a stochastic control problem for a controlled Markov process, and the optimal control is characterised by a function belonging to the domain of the martingale generator. Finally, we give an application to the smooth pasting condition.



rate research

Read More

The aim of this paper is to characterize the Snell envelope of a given P-measurable process l as the minimal solution of some backward stochastic differential equation with lower general reflecting barriers and to prove that this minimal solution exists.
122 - Denis S. Krotov 2019
The Doob scheme $D(m,n+n)$ is a metric association scheme defined on $E_4^m times F_4^{n}times Z_4^{n}$, where $E_4=GR(4^2)$ or, alternatively, on $Z_4^{2m} times Z_2^{2n} times Z_4^{n}$. We prove the MacWilliams identities connecting the weight distributions of a linear or additive code and its dual. In particular, for each case, we determine the dual scheme, on the same set but with different metric, such that the weight distribution of an additive code $C$ in the Doob scheme $D(m,n+n)$ is related by the MacWilliams identities with the weight distribution of the dual code $C^perp$ in the dual scheme. We note that in the case of a linear code $C$ in $E_4^m times F_4^{n}$, the weight distributions of $C$ and $C^perp$ in the same scheme are also connected.
62 - Daniel Lacker 2018
This paper continues the study of the mean field game (MFG) convergence problem: In what sense do the Nash equilibria of $n$-player stochastic differential games converge to the mean field game as $nrightarrowinfty$? Previous work on this problem took two forms. First, when the $n$-player equilibria are open-loop, compactness arguments permit a characterization of all limit points of $n$-player equilibria as weak MFG equilibria, which contain additional randomness compared to the standard (strong) equilibrium concept. On the other hand, when the $n$-player equilibria are closed-loop, the convergence to the MFG equilibrium is known only when the MFG equilibrium is unique and the associated master equation is solvable and sufficiently smooth. This paper adapts the compactness arguments to the closed-loop case, proving a convergence theorem that holds even when the MFG equilibrium is non-unique. Every limit point of $n$-player equilibria is shown to be the same kind of weak MFG equilibrium as in the open-loop case. Some partial results and examples are discussed for the converse question, regarding which of the weak MFG equilibria can arise as the limit of $n$-player (approximate) equilibria.
The stochastic dynamics of biochemical networks are usually modelled with the chemical master equation (CME). The stationary distributions of CMEs are seldom solvable analytically, and numerical methods typically produce estimates with uncontrolled errors. Here, we introduce mathematical programming approaches that yield approximations of these distributions with computable error bounds which enable the verification of their accuracy. First, we use semidefinite programming to compute increasingly tighter upper and lower bounds on the moments of the stationary distributions for networks with rational propensities. Second, we use these moment bounds to formulate linear programs that yield convergent upper and lower bounds on the stationary distributions themselves, their marginals and stationary averages. The bounds obtained also provide a computational test for the uniqueness of the distribution. In the unique case, the bounds form an approximation of the stationary distribution with a computable bound on its error. In the non-unique case, our approach yields converging approximations of the ergodic distributions. We illustrate our methodology through several biochemical examples taken from the literature: Schlogls model for a chemical bifurcation, a two-dimensional toggle switch, a model for bursty gene expression, and a dimerisation model with multiple stationary distributions.
Ensemble methods, such as the ensemble Kalman filter (EnKF), the local ensemble transform Kalman filter (LETKF), and the ensemble Kalman smoother (EnKS) are widely used in sequential data assimilation, where state vectors are of huge dimension. Little is known, however, about the asymptotic behavior of ensemble methods. In this paper, we prove convergence in L^p of ensemble Kalman smoother to the Kalman smoother in the large-ensemble limit, as well as the convergence of EnKS-4DVAR, which is a Levenberg-Marquardt-like algorithm with EnKS as the linear solver, to the classical Levenberg-Marquardt algorithm in which the linearized problem is solved exactly.
comments
Fetching comments Fetching comments
mircosoft-partner

هل ترغب بارسال اشعارات عن اخر التحديثات في شمرا-اكاديميا